The Real-Estate and Transportation Complex
H. William Batt
[Reprinted from
GroundSwell, March-April 2008]
Is there another identifiable "complex" of economic
forces about to be labeled? I'd not be surprised.
It was the "military-industrial complex" that we first
saw identified, now almost half a century ago when President
Eisenhower spoke of its influence in his final address as president.
"This conjunction of an immense military establishment and a
large arms industry is new in the American experience. The total
influence -- economic, political, even spiritual -- is felt in every
city, every State house, every office of the Federal government."
It concerned him greatly. I've read that he'd originally
also included Congress in his identification, but was persuaded to
omit that link in his final wording.
But it's not just this one confluence of economic forces.
The December, 1998, Atlantic Magazine carried a disturbing article
about the "Prison Industrial Complex," a coalition that
includes not just prisons but all the associated law enforcement
bodies in and out of government nationwide. We have over two
million Americans in prison, one person out of every 140 residents.
Law enforcement is very profitable.
Harpers Magazine writer Jonathan Kwitny recounted in a February,
1881 article, titled "The Great Transportation Conspiracy,"
on how, beginning in the mid 1930s, an alliance of General Motors,
Standard Oil, Philips Petroleum, Mack trucks, Firestone Tire and
Rubber and others joined to buy up major bus and trolley services in
our cities, and then scrap them. "Though [their
executives] were all convicted of antitrust violations for what they
did, the token punishments they received -- a one dollar fine! --
scarcely marred the success of their venture.
We have also seen identified the food industry complex, the
medical and insurance industry complex, and the media industry
complex. But we have never recognized one alliance of American
industries that has altered the course of our nation's economy as
much as any. It is the land use complex, perhaps better
understood after a bit of explication. I wrote an article about
eight years ago talking about the triangle of land use,
transportation and taxation.
One could argue that, as United States has become a "service
economy," the combination of industries together classified by
the acronym FIRE -- Finance, Insurance, and Real Estate -- have also
come to wield political influence far beyond either their numerical
strength or their share of GDP. The FIRE sector has maintained
a disproportionate hold on America by successfully imposing its own
political-economic paradigm on the public discourse.
This has grown out of neoclassical economic thinking, but it is
disintegrating before us, just as the FIRE sector reaches the apogee
of its influence. This frame of thinking fails to deal with
our rapidly changing empirical reality, so we have an opportunity to
look anew at how our society and economy operates. We haven't yet
seen the definitive identification of this quickly evolving
configuration. As political and other forces rend it asunder,
another is becoming evident.
But I keep coming back to the alliance between the real-estate and
transportation industries which I believe together are perhaps the
most powerful of all, and yet largely invisible to the general
public. That's because it can't conceive of things any other way.
The relationship between land values and transportation costs has
long been apparent to adherents of Georgist philosophy.
We alone see the cat. It is easy to see that site rent and travel
costs have a reciprocal relationship. Consider the land use
configurations of any urban region, even those as distorted by
artificial pricing as those in America. German geographer Heinrich
von Thunen, who Wikipedia argues to be ranked with Marx for his
acumen, constructed formulas measuring the relationship between land
values and transportation costs. He was focused on the costs farmers
bore to bring their goods to market. To be sure, our metropolises
bear little conformity to the theories of Heinrich von Thunen two
centuries ago, but we generally acknowledge that living "close
in" means lower transportation costs than living out in the "boonies."
We've subsidized transportation so much that the slope is far more
gradual. But we still pay a price in higher land rent for living
closer. Put simply, land rent is the reciprocal of transportation
cost, and land rent can be viewed as capitalized transportation
costs.
One 1998 study showed that for a household in which one worker
drives downtown (or at least to a more central location) to work, a
ten-mile difference may amount to 4,600 miles annually, assuming 230
days of commuting and a round-trip of 20 miles each day. Moreover,
if non-work trips to the central area and elsewhere doubled that
amount; the tradeoff would be just under 10,000 miles annually, not
counting the time saved/spent. The American Automobile Association
calculates now that a car driven 10,000 miles in 2007 cost 62.1
cents per mile, a figure that reflects only direct costs to the
driver, not the additional costs passed on to society. Such are the
savings for living closer to the urban center by ten miles. If the
urban resident were to rely on a car nonetheless, subtracting some
$3,000 annual travel expenses will still leave him paying that much
again (and likely more) to own a car.
A 1993 Natural Resources Defense Council study calculated that the
total costs of motor vehicle transportation to our society equal
approximately a fourth of our gross domestic product (GDP). The
increased price of oil and the cost of keeping the sea lanes open to
bring it to us may have raised that a bit. Just the costs of
automobile crashes represent a figure equal to 8 percent of the
American GDP. Japan, by way of comparison, spends an estimated 10.4
percent to satisfy all its transportation requirements, although the
figure might be a bit low because not all externalities are included
in the calculation. Another study at about the same time concluded
that road user fees were only about a tenth of the true costs to
society; i.e., drivers pay less than 10 percent of the true costs of
their motor vehicle use. The balance is paid by society, effectively
subsidizing highway use by paying for all but the marginal
out-of-pocket operating costs. Because we subsidize motor vehicle
transportation so liberally, we not only foster congestion, we also
build more pressure for continued highway expansion. And of course
this undercuts the use of public transportation and fosters sprawl
development.
With an administration in Washington now very sympathetic to oil
interests, there has been a dearth of studies updating some of this
data. But one would expect that the costs have grown exponentially.
Another way to look at the significance of motor vehicle
transportation in the US is by the number or percentage of
employees. I've read or heard that one in six Americans earn their
living in some way related to roads or cars. That means so many more
people shuttling ourselves, or things, around that can't be employed
in some more productive way. It means either longer work hours and
less leisure time for us, or lower quality of life. To neoclassical
economists who measure well being by the size of the GDP or per
capita income, it matters not how efficient or inefficient our
economy is. But as the "peak oil" crisis looms nearer and
larger, such considerations will weigh more heavily.
Consider first the transportation side of the equation. The
farther away we live from urban cores the more it costs to travel,
not just in time but in cost, especially energy. Moreover, we've
configured our metropolitan regions in a way that they almost have
ceased to have an urban core; we often need to travel from suburb to
suburb as we go downtown. Indeed, given the intractability of land
use configurations one doesn't easily alter infrastructure once it's
put in place we may be stuck with what we've imposed. Foolishly,
we've created one class of land improvements for work and commerce,
and another class for living space linked with an expensive
commuting network. What happens when transportation becomes still
more expensive?
Now look at the structure for locational choices. Prices are one
of the key determinates of our decisions, as they should be. But
many of us live in remote areas because we can't afford to live
downtown we'd rather commute, because society is picking up much of
the cost. Locations in site rent -- aren't subsidized to equilibrate
transportation. Even with subsidized commutes, the land value
gradients from center to periphery are huge. I've been interested in
portraying this using GIS to make land value scapes for a decade.
For our CGO conference in DesMoines, I portrayed the difference in
site values for Polk County.
How might it be possible to make the urban downtowns affordable so
that we don't have that travel cost? How can we equilibrate the
costs of the center and the periphery? The answer is easy: collect
the site rent. Right now, we pay the travel costs as our needs
arise, but we only pay the site rent the capitalized site rent at
that -- when we buy our homes. Ground rent is a flow every bit as
much as is travel expense. Capturing both at the same time would
equalize the burdens, making the costs competitive. Of course we
would need to remove the public subsidies for travel so that the
marginal costs were comparable. But that's doable: it involves
capturing the site rent in taxes, and pricing travel for the
commuter at its true cost.
But getting back to the real estate and transportation alliance,
or complex if you will. The best way I know to show how dominant
these sectors of the economy are in our lives is to look at their
share of total newspaper advertising. For the most recent year
available, 2005, the Real Estate industry expenditure on newspaper
advertising was 26.8 percent. For the auto industry, it was another
26.5 percent. The only other significant share was for employment:
29.6 percent. We are seduced into spending an enormous amount of our
budgets on cars and homes.
If a transformation of our economy is to occur, it is clear that
these two industries are the ones that will be most threatened.
The encouraging thought is that we can’t continue on the
path that we are on: change will be either by our collective
choice or by forces beyond our control.